economics tuition singapore | top JC economics tutor | etg econs tuition | h2 economics tuition

View Original

Explain why museums are not public goods, but the government considers it necessary to intervene in the market for museums.

The ETG Ultimate Exam Pack is designed to give you the intensive revision you need for A-Level Economics. With 71% of ETG students scoring an A in 2023, this pack includes 6-8 highly efficient days of revision through crash courses, mock exams, and a final consolidation lecture with predictions. From tackling complex concepts to perfecting your essays, this pack covers it all. You’ll have access to resources like Microeconomics and Macroeconomics Express textbooks, 50 model essays, and CSQ Bootcamp videos. Structured mock exams and workshops will help you overcome exam challenges, while exclusive materials, recorded lessons, and concise guides ensure you're fully prepared for the exams. With Mr. Toh’s accurate predictions, you can approach the A-Levels with confidence.


Museums are important cultural institutions that enrich communities and benefit even non-visitors. They often rely on government subsidies to keep ticket prices affordable for as many segments of society as possible. However, as some museums prosper and attract large crowds, there is growing debate over reducing subsidies to reallocate funds elsewhere.

(a) Explain why museums are not public goods, but the government considers it necessary to intervene in the market for museums. [10]

Introduction

For a good to be classified as a public good, it must possess specific characteristics: non-excludability, non-rivalry in consumption, and non-rejectability. Museums, while important cultural institutions that provide benefits to both visitors and non-visitors, do not meet these criteria and are therefore not public goods.

Non-excludability: This means that once the good is provided, it is impossible to exclude individuals from consuming it. For example, national defence is a public good because it protects everyone, and no one can be excluded from benefiting from it.

Non-rivalry in consumption: This implies that one person’s consumption of the good does not diminish the amount available for others. For instance, a lighthouse serves all ships passing by, and one ship’s benefit does not reduce the benefit available to others.

Non-rejectability: This means that individuals cannot choose to reject the good. For example, even if someone does not wish to benefit from street lighting, they cannot opt out of it.

Museums Are Not Public Goods

Museums, while beneficial, do not meet the criteria of public goods:

Museums are excludable because entry barriers can be imposed. Museums typically charge an entrance fee, meaning only those who pay are allowed to access the exhibitions. This creates an exclusion mechanism, making museums different from true public goods, where access cannot be restricted.

Museums are also rivalrous to some degree. Although multiple visitors can enjoy the exhibits simultaneously, there are limits to how many people a museum can accommodate at any given time. If too many people visit, overcrowding can reduce the enjoyment and quality of the experience for others, creating rivalry in consumption.


Museums are also rejectable in the sense that individuals can choose whether or not to visit. Unlike public goods such as national defence, where individuals cannot opt out of its benefits, a person may choose not to consume the services offered by a museum.

Therefore, museums do not fulfil the criteria of non-excludability, non-rivalry, or non-rejectability, which are essential characteristics of public goods.

Museums are merit goods (which is why government intervenes)

Although museums are not public goods, governments often intervene in the market for museums because they are considered merit goods. Merit goods are deemed socially desirable by the government but tend to be underconsumed in a free market. This underconsumption occurs because the private benefits received by individuals are lower than the overall social benefits that these goods provide.

Museums generate positive externalities, meaning that the consumption of museum services produces benefits that extend beyond the individual consumer and spill over to society as a whole. A positive externality is defined as a situation where a third party benefits from the consumption or production of a good or service. For example, when someone visits a museum and learns about their country’s history, they may develop a deeper sense of national identity and unity, which can positively affect the broader community. Additionally, the knowledge gained from a museum visit can be shared with others who have not visited the museum, amplifying its societal benefits.

In the absence of government intervention, individuals consume museums at Qm, the level where their marginal private cost (MPC) equals their marginal private benefit (MPB). MPC represents the cost borne by an individual to visit the museum, such as the ticket price and travel expenses. MPB represents the individual’s personal satisfaction or utility from visiting the museum. However, the presence of positive externalities means that the marginal social benefit (MSB)—which includes both the private benefit and the external benefit to society—exceeds the MPB. The divergence between MSB and MPB leads to underconsumption of museums at Qm, which is lower than the socially optimal level of consumption Qs, where marginal social cost (MSC) equals marginal social benefit (MSB).

Because individuals only consider their private benefits and costs, they tend to underconsume merit goods like museums, leading to a situation where the market fails to allocate resources efficiently. This underconsumption creates a deadweight loss, representing the lost social welfare due to the fact that museums are consumed at suboptimal levels.

Conclusion

To correct this market failure, the government typically intervenes by providing subsidies or funding to museums. By lowering the cost of museum visits, the government encourages greater consumption, moving the quantity consumed closer to the socially optimal level Qs. Subsidies reduce the MPC, aligning it more closely with the MSB and allowing more people to benefit from museum services.