Asymmetric Information

This chapter will explore asymmetric information as a significant cause of market failure, focusing on two key concepts: adverse selection and moral hazard. These occur when one party in a transaction has more information than the other, leading to inefficient outcomes. We will delve into how asymmetric information affects markets, specifically through second-hand car markets and healthcare insurance markets, and discuss how governments try to resolve these issues. However, we will also highlight the limitations and failures of such interventions. Real-world examples will help clarify these concepts.

1. Introduction to Asymmetric Information and Market Failure

In economics, market failure refers to situations where markets fail to allocate resources efficiently, leading to a loss of welfare. One of the primary causes of market failure is asymmetric information, where one party in a transaction possesses more or better information than the other. This imbalance can lead to inefficiencies such as overproduction or underproduction of goods and services. For example, in the used car market, the seller may know more about the quality of the car than the buyer, which can cause buyers to make suboptimal decisions. This chapter will explain how such imbalances lead to market inefficiency and how governments attempt to address these failures.

2. Understanding Asymmetric Information

2.1 Definition of Asymmetric Information

Asymmetric information occurs when one party in a transaction has more or better information than the other party. This can result in market inefficiency, as the less-informed party makes decisions based on incomplete or incorrect information.

For instance, in the case of buying a used car, the seller knows more about the car’s condition than the buyer. The buyer might either overpay for a faulty car or avoid purchasing altogether, even if the car is in good condition. This leads to an inefficient outcome.

Key Characteristics of Asymmetric Information:

  • Information Imbalance: One party holds more or better information, creating an imbalance.

  • Impact on Decision Making: The less-informed party makes decisions based on incorrect or incomplete data.

  • Market Inefficiency: The resulting decisions can cause resources to be misallocated, leading to underproduction or overproduction.

3. Adverse Selection

Adverse selection occurs when one party in a transaction has better information than the other, leading to bad outcomes. In markets, adverse selection often arises in situations where buyers cannot differentiate between high-quality and low-quality goods or services.

3.1 Second-Hand Car Markets (The "Lemon Problem")

Adverse selection in second-hand car markets is often referred to as the "lemon problem". In these markets, sellers usually know more about the car’s quality than buyers. This information imbalance can cause buyers to offer lower prices, assuming that most cars will be of low quality ("lemons").

  • Real-World Example:
    Imagine you are buying a used car. The seller knows whether the car has any defects or issues, but you, as the buyer, have no way of knowing. As a result, you might offer a lower price, not willing to pay top dollar for a car you cannot fully trust. In turn, sellers with high-quality cars might withdraw from the market because they are unable to get a fair price for their cars. This leaves only the low-quality cars ("lemons") on the market.

  • Market Outcome:

    • This causes a reduction in the number of transactions in the used car market, with fewer buyers and fewer sellers. It reduces market efficiency and welfare because good quality cars are driven out by bad ones.

3.2 Healthcare Insurance Markets

In healthcare insurance markets, adverse selection happens when individuals who are most likely to need medical care are also the ones most likely to purchase health insurance. This creates an imbalanced risk pool that leads to higher premiums and rising costs for the entire market.

  • Example:
    Consider a situation where someone suffering from chronic illness is more likely to purchase health insurance, while healthy individuals may not see the need to buy insurance. As a result, the insurance company faces a disproportionate number of sick policyholders, which increases the insurer's costs. These increased costs may cause insurance premiums to rise, discouraging healthier individuals from buying coverage. As fewer healthy individuals join the insurance pool, the cycle continues, making the insurance market less efficient.

  • Real-World Example:
    In private health insurance markets, insurers face difficulty attracting a balanced pool of policyholders. Without mandatory health insurance or regulations to limit discriminatory pricing, insurance premiums may increase, making it more difficult for the market to operate efficiently.

Adverse Selection in Healthcare Insurance

Adverse selection is a pervasive issue in insurance markets, including healthcare insurance. It arises when individuals with a higher risk profile—those more likely to make an insurance claim—are more inclined to buy insurance. This disproportionate representation of riskier individuals in the insurance pool can lead to market destabilisation.

For instance, consider a pool of insured individuals comprising smokers and non-smokers. The smokers, who are at a higher risk of contracting illnesses such as cancer, would logically require higher coverage. Let's assume there are 100 smokers, each contributing $1,000 to a mutual fund for potential cancer treatment, totaling $100,000. Non-smokers, with a lower risk, only need to contribute $500 each since they are less likely to contract cancer, creating a fund of $50,000 for the same number of individuals.

However, if smokers misrepresent themselves as non-smokers to avail of the lower premiums, it disrupts the balance of the insurance pool. The cost of insuring the supposed non-smokers inflates because of the increased risk. Consequently, real non-smokers may deem the insurance poor value for money, causing them to leave the insurance market altogether. This withdrawal amplifies the adverse selection problem, leading to a market dominated by high-risk individuals and potentially higher insurance premiums.

3.3 Government Intervention to Resolve Adverse Selection

Governments often intervene to correct the imbalance caused by adverse selection. Common solutions include mandatory insurance, subsidies, and regulation.

  • Mandatory Insurance:
    Governments may require individuals to purchase insurance, ensuring that both healthy and sick people are included in the risk pool.

    • Example: The Affordable Care Act (ACA) in the U.S. introduced a mandate that requires all individuals to have health insurance. This was aimed at preventing adverse selection by ensuring a broader, more balanced pool of insured individuals.

  • Subsidies:
    Governments can offer subsidies to make insurance more affordable for individuals who might otherwise avoid purchasing it. This can help maintain a healthy balance in the risk pool.

    • Example: Singapore's MediShield Life is a national health insurance plan that offers subsidized premiums for low-income individuals.

  • Regulation:
    Governments can also regulate insurance companies to prevent them from discriminating against people based on pre-existing conditions.

    • Example: The U.K.’s National Health Service (NHS) provides universal health insurance to all citizens, eliminating the risk of adverse selection.

3.4 Government Failure in Addressing Adverse Selection

While government interventions can reduce adverse selection, they are not always successful.

  • Health Insurance Subsidies:
    Although subsidies can help lower premiums, they may also lead to people buying unnecessary or excessive coverage, further increasing costs for the system.

    • Example: Free healthcare may encourage overuse of medical services, putting strain on public resources.

4. Moral Hazard

Moral hazard occurs when individuals take on more risks because they do not bear the full consequences of their actions, often because they are protected by insurance or government programs.

4.1 Moral Hazard in Healthcare Insurance Markets

Moral hazard is most apparent in healthcare insurance markets, where individuals with insurance might seek excessive medical treatment because they are not responsible for the full cost.

  • Example:
    An insured individual might visit the doctor for minor ailments or request unnecessary medical treatments simply because they know the insurance will cover the costs. This leads to overconsumption of healthcare services, driving up costs for both insurers and the healthcare system as a whole.

  • Real-World Example:
    In countries with universal healthcare, such as the U.K., some individuals may overuse medical services simply because they do not directly bear the cost. For example, visiting the doctor for minor issues that could be treated at home may strain public healthcare resources.

Moral Hazard Problem in Healthcare Insurance

In the realm of healthcare insurance, moral hazard arises when individuals with insurance coverage alter their behaviour, leading to increased utilization of healthcare services. This is due to the psychological security provided by insurance, insulating individuals from the full cost of healthcare.

Design Note: A visual depiction of an individual with healthcare insurance indulging in risky behaviour, like overeating or smoking, knowing well that their insurance will cover the potential health issues, could effectively portray the concept of moral hazard.

Suppose an individual possesses comprehensive healthcare insurance. With this financial safety net, the perceived cost of additional healthcare services—additional blood tests, MRIs, medication, or further doctor visits—can appear insignificant. This perception, detached from the real cost of services, catalyses an overuse of healthcare facilities and services.

Moreover, insured individuals may neglect their health, knowing that they have insurance to fall back on. This change in behaviour and attitude towards personal health can lead to increased long-term healthcare costs, putting additional pressure on the healthcare system.

The impact of moral hazard isn't limited to individual behaviour; it also exerts considerable strain on the healthcare insurance market. The overuse of healthcare services spikes demand, which subsequently increases healthcare costs. As these costs inflate, insurance companies are forced to hike up premiums to cover their liabilities, perpetuating a vicious cycle of cost escalation. Eventually, the insurance premiums may become unaffordable for many, leading them to exit the market. 

4.2 Government Intervention to Address Moral Hazard

To address moral hazard, governments often introduce measures like co-payments or incentive programs.

  • Co-Payments:
    By requiring individuals to contribute a small amount for medical services, governments can help reduce the incentive for unnecessary medical visits.

    • Example: Singapore’s Medisave and MediShield Life introduce co-payments for treatments, ensuring that people bear some responsibility for their healthcare costs.

  • Incentive Programs:
    Governments may also introduce programs that reward healthy behaviors to reduce the demand for healthcare services.

    • Example: Wellness Programs in health insurance policies can offer discounts to individuals who meet certain health criteria.

4.3 Government Failure in Addressing Moral Hazard

Despite these interventions, governments may fail to completely mitigate moral hazard.

  • Free Healthcare and Overuse:
    Even with co-payments, people might still overuse medical services if the coverage is too generous or if incentives are ineffective in changing behavior.

5. Conclusion

Asymmetric information, through adverse selection and moral hazard, is a critical cause of market failure. Governments often step in to correct these inefficiencies, but their interventions can sometimes lead to unintended consequences. Understanding the dynamics of asymmetric information is essential for designing policies that can improve market outcomes and ensure better resource allocation.

Discussion Questions

  1. How can adverse selection be mitigated in other markets, such as the labor market or real estate?

  2. What are the potential downsides of requiring individuals to purchase health insurance?

  3. How can governments better address the issue of moral hazard in the healthcare system?


If you're looking for top-tier economics tuition in Singapore, the ETG Economics Tuition program offers specialized classes designed to help students excel in their A Level or IB Economics exams. Led by Mr. Eugene Toh, a highly experienced economics tutor with double Master's degrees, ETG focuses exclusively on A Level and IB Economics. With a proven track record, 71% of ETG's A Level Economics students achieved an 'A' grade in 2023, and over 90% from top junior colleges like Raffles Institution (RI), Hwa Chong Institution (HCI), and Nanyang Junior College (NJC) also scored an 'A'.

At ETG, we offer more than just standard econs tuition – our students gain access to exclusive learning materials like in-house textbooks, guidebooks, and essay banks developed by Mr. Toh and the academic team. With a flexible learning environment, including options for both onsite and online economics tuition, students can learn at their convenience. We also provide graded homework, consultations with Mr. Toh, and the opportunity for early registrants to access additional resources like the Essay and CSQ Booster course.

Take a look at our stunningly curated textbooks, exclusively available for ETG students only: